In an era defined by a relentless barrage of economic shocks—from the global financial crisis of 2008 to the unprecedented disruptions of the COVID-19 pandemic and the escalating climate emergency—the once-dominant paradigms of economic thought have been found wanting. For decades, macroeconomics has been largely guided by models built on the assumption of a stable world, where economies, if perturbed, would naturally return to a single, predictable equilibrium. This comforting notion, however, has been shattered by the volatile reality of the 21st century, leaving policymakers and economists scrambling for new tools to navigate a world of radical uncertainty and complex, interconnected systems.
Out of this intellectual crucible, a new way of thinking is emerging, one that seeks to move beyond the elegant but often unrealistic assumptions of the past. This nascent paradigm, christened "MEADE" by its proponents, offers a framework for understanding an economy characterized by multiple possible futures and a diversity of interacting agents. Standing for Multiple Equilibrium And DiversE, the MEADE paradigm is not just a minor tweak to existing models; it represents a fundamental shift in how we conceptualize and engage with the economic world. It is an approach that acknowledges the messy, unpredictable, and often surprising nature of economic life, offering a more robust and realistic toolkit for a world that refuses to stand still.
The Crumbling Foundations of Equilibrium Economics
For the better part of a century, mainstream macroeconomics has been built upon the bedrock of general equilibrium theory. First formalized by Léon Walras in the 19th century and later refined by economists like Kenneth Arrow and Gérard Debreu, this theory attempts to explain the behavior of supply, demand, and prices in a whole economy with multiple interacting markets. The core idea is that, through the flexible movement of prices, all markets will eventually "clear," meaning supply will equal demand, leading to a stable and efficient state known as a general equilibrium.
This framework reached its modern apotheosis in the New Keynesian Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (NK-DSGE) models, which have dominated macroeconomic research and policymaking for the last two decades. These models, while mathematically sophisticated, are built on a set of highly idealized assumptions:
- A single, stable equilibrium: The economy is assumed to have one equilibrium state to which it will always return after a temporary shock.
- Rational, representative agents: The model typically assumes that the economy can be understood by modeling the behavior of a single, "representative" individual or firm that is perfectly rational, well-informed, and consistently makes optimal decisions to maximize its own utility or profit.
- Perfect information and frictionless markets: The models often assume that all economic actors have complete information about the present and future, and that markets operate without frictions like transaction costs or financing constraints.
These assumptions allow for the creation of elegant and mathematically tractable models. However, the 21st century's series of crises has brutally exposed their limitations. The 2008 global financial crisis, a cataclysm that the vast majority of mainstream macroeconomists failed to predict, served as a stark wake-up call. The subsequent slow and painful recovery, often hampered by austerity policies justified by these same models, further eroded confidence in the prevailing paradigm.
Critics argue that the NK-DSGE framework is fundamentally unsuited to understanding large economic shocks for several reasons:
- It cannot account for phenomena like financial panics, market crashes, or prolonged depressions, where the economy can get stuck in a "bad" state for an extended period.
- The assumption of a single equilibrium is a "major diversion from reality," as it ignores the possibility that a large shock can permanently alter the structure of the economy, pushing it onto a completely different path.
- The "analytical straight-jacket" of perfect rationality and representative agents prevents the models from recognizing that real-world decisions are made under profound uncertainty and are shaped by psychology, heuristics, and social interactions.
As Oxford economist David Vines, a key proponent of the MEADE paradigm, starkly puts it, "The old model of 'macroeconomics' was built for a stable world free from large economic shocks. If we ever lived in such a world, we no longer do." An economic model that cannot handle serious shocks is likened to a medical science that doesn't study major diseases—it is destined to fail when it is needed most.
The Dawn of the MEADE Paradigm
In response to this crisis in macroeconomics, David Vines and Samuel Wills, both from the University of Oxford, have championed the "Rebuilding Macroeconomic Theory Project." This collaborative effort brings together leading economists, including Nobel laureate Joseph Stiglitz, to forge a new path forward. The MEADE paradigm is the conceptual framework that has emerged from this project, representing a significant departure from the old consensus.
The name itself is a tribute to the Nobel prize-winning British economist James Meade (1907-1995). While the paradigm doesn't directly adapt Meade's specific models, it is deeply inspired by his intellectual spirit. Meade was a pragmatic economist who believed in using the tools of economic analysis to solve real-world problems and design a better, fairer society. He was instrumental in the Keynesian revolution, helping to develop the concept of the multiplier and the first modern set of national accounts. His work on international trade and the balance of payments, for which he won the Nobel Prize in 1977, was marked by a careful consideration of policy objectives and the tools required to achieve them. It is this practical, policy-oriented, and intellectually honest approach that the MEADE paradigm seeks to emulate.
The MEADE paradigm is built on two foundational pillars that directly challenge the old framework:
- Multiple Equilibria (ME): The first and most crucial departure is the explicit recognition that economies can have more than one stable outcome, or equilibrium. Rather than a single point of stability, the economy might face several possible states, and a shock or a policy intervention could be the catalyst that shifts it from one to another. This concept is not entirely new, but the MEADE paradigm elevates it from a curious exception to a central organizing principle of macroeconomic analysis.
- Diverse Models (DE): To understand a world with multiple equilibria, a single, all-encompassing model is no longer sufficient. The MEADE paradigm advocates for a more pluralistic and diverse approach to modeling. This involves using a range of different models, each suited to answering different questions and illuminating different aspects of the complex economic reality. As Vines and Wills argue, just as a doctor uses a whole host of diagnostic tools to understand the human body, economists must use a wide range of empirically-grounded models to understand the functioning of an economy.
This dual focus on multiple equilibria and diverse modeling represents a move towards a macroeconomics that is "less tied to idealised theoretical assumptions, takes real-world data more seriously, and is, therefore, far better suited to dealing with 21st century challenges."
Understanding a World of Multiple Equilibria
The concept of multiple equilibria can seem abstract, but it has concrete and intuitive applications that explain many real-world economic phenomena.
A classic example is a bank run. An economy can have two stable equilibria for its banking system. In the "good" equilibrium, depositors are confident in the bank's solvency and only withdraw money when they need it for transactions. The bank remains liquid and can continue its function of channeling savings into productive investment. However, a "bad" equilibrium also exists. If depositors lose confidence and believe the bank might fail, they will all rush to withdraw their funds simultaneously. Even a fundamentally sound bank cannot withstand such a panic, as it holds only a fraction of its deposits in liquid cash. The bank fails, validating the initial pessimistic beliefs. This is a self-fulfilling prophecy, and it demonstrates how the economy can be tipped from a good equilibrium to a bad one by a shift in expectations, which could be triggered by a "sunspot"—an event that is fundamentally irrelevant to the economy's health but coordinates people's beliefs.
Other examples abound:
- Technology Adoption: In markets with increasing returns to scale, the success of a new technology often depends on how many other people are using it (network effects). This can lead to multiple equilibria. One equilibrium might see a superior technology failing to gain a foothold simply because an inferior one got an early lead. Another could see a critical mass of early adopters pushing a new standard to dominance.
- Development Traps: A developing country might be stuck in a "poverty trap"—a low-growth equilibrium characterized by low investment, poor infrastructure, and weak institutions. The lack of investment perpetuates the conditions that make investment unattractive. However, a "big push" of coordinated investment and institutional reform could potentially shift the economy to a high-growth equilibrium with robust development.
- Labor Markets: Labor markets can exhibit multiple equilibria. One equilibrium could be characterized by high wages, high skills, and low unemployment. Another could be a low-wage, low-skill equilibrium where firms have no incentive to invest in training and workers have no incentive to acquire skills.
By focusing on these possibilities, the MEADE paradigm shifts the role of policy. In a single-equilibrium world, the goal of policy is to smooth out fluctuations around that single state. In a multiple-equilibrium world, the role of policy becomes more profound: it is about equilibrium selection. The goal is to design policies that make bad equilibria less likely or impossible, and that help steer the economy towards the most desirable outcome. For instance, deposit insurance is a policy designed to eliminate the bad equilibrium of a bank run by removing the incentive for depositors to panic.
The Power of Diverse Models: From "Toys" to Policy Tools
To navigate this world of multiple equilibria, the MEADE paradigm proposes a diverse and eclectic modeling strategy, moving away from the reliance on a single "core" model like the NK-DSGE. This strategy involves two main types of models: "toy models" and "policy models."
Toy Models:The term "toy model," coined by economists, refers to simple, highly stylized models designed to provide a "quick, first-pass, intuitive understanding of a question." They are not meant to be realistic representations of the entire economy. Instead, they strip away complexity to isolate and clarify a specific mechanism or idea.
Vines and Wills argue that many of the most influential models in the history of macroeconomics have been, in essence, toy models:
- The IS-LM model, which provided generations of students with a basic framework for understanding the interaction between goods and money markets.
- The Solow-Swan growth model, which offered a simple and powerful way to think about the roles of capital accumulation, population growth, and technological progress in the long run.
- Even the benchmark NK-DSGE model, they now contend, should be understood as a toy model rather than a "core model" capable of explaining everything. Its value lies in elucidating the logic of a particular set of assumptions, not in its empirical realism.
Within the MEADE paradigm, the role of toy models is crucial. They are the sketchpads where economists can explore the mechanisms that give rise to multiple equilibria. By creating simple, often two-dimensional diagrams, they can clearly show how factors like strategic complementarities, feedback loops, or increasing returns can lead to a situation where more than one outcome is possible.
Policy Models:While toy models are essential for intuition, they are insufficient for detailed policy analysis. This is where "policy models" come in. These are larger, more complex, and empirically grounded models that aim to capture the detailed reality of a specific economy. They are built with a "closer fidelity to the data" and incorporate a much richer institutional and behavioral detail.
The idea is to create a dynamic interplay between the two types of models. The simple toy models provide the theoretical insights and mechanisms, which can then be incorporated and tested within the larger, more realistic policy models. This approach avoids the trap of having a single, monolithic model that is expected to do everything, and instead fosters a more flexible and adaptive research program.
Beyond the Paradigm: Complexity Economics and Agent-Based Modeling
The MEADE paradigm, with its focus on multiple equilibria and diverse agents, finds a natural and powerful ally in the burgeoning fields of complexity economics and agent-based modeling (ABM). These approaches provide the tools and the conceptual framework to build the very kinds of models that MEADE advocates for.
Complexity economics views the economy not as a system in equilibrium, but as a complex adaptive system. It studies how the economy's macroscopic patterns, like growth rates, inflation, and business cycles, emerge from the bottom-up interactions of a diverse population of adaptive agents. Key tenets of complexity economics that resonate with the MEADE paradigm include:- Non-Equilibrium as the Natural State: The economy is seen as being in a constant state of flux, always evolving and creating new structures and patterns. Equilibrium is a special, and often uninteresting, case.
- Fundamental Uncertainty: Agents operate not with perfect information, but in a world of deep uncertainty where they must make decisions based on evolving beliefs and expectations.
- Endogenous Change: The system generates its own change from within, through processes like technological innovation and the co-evolution of strategies, rather than just reacting to external shocks.
The power of ABM lies in its ability to simulate how the interactions of these heterogeneous agents, each following their own rules, can lead to complex and often surprising macroeconomic outcomes. For example, an agent-based model of a financial market can show how the interaction of different trading strategies can give rise to phenomena like speculative bubbles and market crashes—outcomes that are difficult to explain with traditional equilibrium models.
The synergy between MEADE and ABM is clear. The MEADE paradigm calls for a move away from the representative agent and towards models that embrace heterogeneity and real-world behavior; ABM provides a direct way to do this. The MEADE paradigm emphasizes the importance of multiple equilibria and emergent phenomena; ABMs are perfectly suited to exploring how these arise from micro-level interactions. By incorporating ABM into their diverse toolkit, proponents of the MEADE paradigm can build the empirically-grounded, non-equilibrium models needed to understand our volatile world.
Policy in a Volatile World: A New Compass
Adopting the MEADE paradigm has profound implications for economic policy. It requires a shift away from the idea that policymakers are simply fine-tuning a machine that will reliably return to a stable state. Instead, it suggests that policymakers are more like gardeners, tending to a complex ecosystem that can flourish in different ways or collapse unexpectedly.
From Fine-Tuning to Resilience:The focus of policy shifts from optimizing around a single equilibrium to building resilience and promoting "equilibrium selection." This means:
- Identifying and Mitigating Risks of "Bad Equilibria": Policymakers must focus on understanding the mechanisms that could tip the economy into a disastrous state. This involves stress-testing the financial system not for small shocks, but for the kind of "doom loop" feedback mechanisms that can lead to a full-blown crisis. It means designing regulations that act as firebreaks to prevent panics from spreading.
- Creating an Environment for "Good Equilibria": Policy can be used to create the conditions that make desirable outcomes more likely. For example, public investment in green technology and infrastructure can help create a "good" equilibrium where the economy shifts to a sustainable growth path, overcoming the inertia of the fossil fuel-based system.
- Adaptive Management: In a complex and uncertain world, the idea of a single, optimal policy set in advance is an illusion. Policymaking needs to be more adaptive and experimental. This involves implementing policies, carefully observing their effects on the complex system, and being prepared to adjust them as the economy evolves.
The MEADE framework also calls for a rethinking of the traditional roles of fiscal and monetary policy. In a world of multiple equilibria, especially near the "zero lower bound" where interest rates cannot be cut further, the effectiveness of these tools can change dramatically.
- Fiscal Policy's Renewed Importance: In a deep recession, which can be seen as a "bad" equilibrium, fiscal policy (government spending and taxation) may become much more powerful. A large fiscal stimulus might be the "big push" needed to jolt the economy out of a slump and back to a high-employment equilibrium, something that monetary policy alone may be unable to achieve.
- Monetary Policy and Financial Stability: Monetary policy can no longer focus solely on inflation and employment. It must also take financial stability into account. This is because low interest rates, while intended to stimulate the economy, can also fuel asset bubbles and create financial fragilities that increase the risk of a crisis, potentially tipping the economy into a very bad equilibrium.
Challenges and Criticisms: Is MEADE Revolutionary Enough?
Despite its promise, the MEADE paradigm is not without its critics. The most significant critique comes from economists who argue that, while it moves in the right direction, it may not be radical enough. The core of this criticism, articulated by economists like Servaas Storm, is that the MEADE paradigm's continued reliance on DSGE models, even in a modified form, means it is still tied to a flawed foundation.
The critique centers on the MEADE proponents' suggestion that the mechanisms for multiple equilibria discovered in simple toy models should then be incorporated into larger DSGE models that are "properly micro-founded." The term "micro-foundations" in mainstream economics has come to mean deriving macroeconomic relationships from the optimization problems of rational, forward-looking agents. Critics argue that as long as the MEADE paradigm adheres to this principle, it will inherit the fundamental weaknesses of the DSGE framework and fail to be truly revolutionary.
In essence, the argument is that you cannot fix a broken foundation by building a more elaborate structure on top of it. If the core assumptions about agent behavior and market clearing are unrealistic, then simply allowing the resulting model to have more than one solution does not solve the underlying problem. For these critics, a true paradigm shift would require abandoning the DSGE framework altogether and fully embracing alternative approaches like agent-based modeling or Post-Keynesian economics, which are built on entirely different micro-foundations from the start.
The Road Ahead: Economics Beyond a Single Future
The debate surrounding the MEADE paradigm is more than an arcane academic squabble. It strikes at the heart of how we understand and shape our economic future. The series of crises that have marked the 21st century have demonstrated with brutal clarity that the old certainties are gone. We live in a world of volatility, complexity, and radical uncertainty—a world for which our existing economic maps are dangerously out of date.
The MEADE paradigm offers a new compass for this new territory. By embracing the possibility of multiple economic futures and championing a diverse, empirically-grounded approach to modeling, it pushes the boundaries of mainstream economic thought in a direction that is both necessary and long overdue. It encourages economists to be more humble about the limits of their knowledge and more creative in their search for solutions.
Whether MEADE will ultimately be seen as a truly new paradigm or a transitional phase on the way to something even more revolutionary remains to be seen. The critiques of its lingering attachment to the DSGE framework are serious and must be addressed. However, by placing the concepts of multiple equilibria and model diversity at the center of the conversation, the architects of the MEADE paradigm have initiated a vital process of rebuilding. They are forcing the economics profession to look beyond the comforting illusion of a single, stable equilibrium and to confront the messy, unpredictable, yet ultimately more realistic world we all inhabit. In doing so, they are not just rethinking economic theory; they are forging the tools we need to navigate the turbulent waters of the 21st century and to actively choose a more prosperous and resilient economic future.
Reference:
- https://www.ubs.com/microsites/nobel-perspectives/en/laureates/james-meade.html
- https://www.christs.cam.ac.uk/james-meade-1907-1995
- https://www.ox.ac.uk/news/2021-01-20-21st-century-crises-demand-new-economic-understanding-say-top-economists
- https://www.oxfordmartin.ox.ac.uk/news/21st-century-crises-demand-new-economic-understanding
- https://www.ineteconomics.org/perspectives/blog/rethinking-macro-theory
- https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/wp9862.pdf
- http://pinguet.free.fr/vineswills.pdf
- https://www.economic-instability.com/?p=276
- https://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/bios/Meade.html
- https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/James_Meade
- https://samuelwills.net/wp-content/uploads/2021/01/vineswills2020.pdf
- https://www.nber.org/system/files/chapters/c11056/c11056.pdf
- https://invezz.com/definitions/multiple-equilibrium/
- https://www.journals.uchicago.edu/doi/full/10.1086/725792
- https://www.inet.ox.ac.uk/publications/the-rebuilding-macroeconomic-theory-project-part-ii-multiple-equilibria-toy-models-and-policy-models-in-a-new-macroeconomic-paradigm
- https://www.semanticscholar.org/paper/0d8fd29eaec3ae1b1e2eb5a17eadb322b2922cba
- https://www.bankofengland.co.uk/-/media/boe/files/quarterly-bulletin/2016/agent-based-models-understanding-the-economy-from-the-bottom-up.pdf
- https://www.google.com/search?q=time+in+Meade+County,+US
- https://www.researchgate.net/publication/348617601_The_rebuilding_macroeconomic_theory_project_part_II_Multiple_equilibria_toy_models_and_policy_models_in_a_new_macroeconomic_paradigm
- https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/107317/1/MPRA_paper_107317.pdf
- https://journals.openedition.org/oeconomia/8222
- https://d-nb.info/1151638439/34
- https://www.investopedia.com/ask/answers/040315/how-do-fiscal-and-monetary-policies-affect-aggregate-demand.asp
- https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=eHtSNQI4Fnc
- https://openaccess.city.ac.uk/id/eprint/25573/23/Steinbacher2021_Article_AdvancesInTheAgent-basedModeli.pdf
- https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=6Mg587xTNwQ
- https://www.tandfonline.com/doi/abs/10.1080/08911916.2021.1929582
- https://www.tandfonline.com/doi/full/10.1080/08911916.2021.1929582